test

Understanding Cooperative Finance as a New Common?
Anaïs Périlleux  1, 2@  , Marthe Nyssens  4, 3, *@  
1 : Université Catholique de Louvain  (UCL)  -  Site web
Place de l'Université 1 Louvain-la-Neuve -  Belgique
2 : Centre for European Research in Microfinance  (Cermi)  -  Site web
Universite Libre de Bruxelles 1050 Brussels -  Belgique
4 : Centre Interdisciplinaire de Recherche Travail, État et Société  (CIRTES)  -  Site web
6, Boulevard Devreux B-6000 Charleroi (Belgique) -  Belgique
3 : Université Catholique de Louvain  (UCL)  -  Site web
Place de l'Université 1 - 1348 Louvain-La-Neuve -  Belgique
* : Auteur correspondant

Abstract

The world currently face three major crises: a financial crisis, which has dramatic consequences for the real economy, an environmental crisis resulting from global warming and a social crisis with a general increase in social and economic inequalities. These crises urge for a shift toward more sustainable ways of producing and consuming. The emerging economics of common good is promising in order to preserve common natural goods that are vital for humanity, such as air, water or food, but also goods created by humans from collective action. A new generation of commons has to be defined and recognized.

The Great Financial Crisis of 2007-2009 has stressed the urgency of strengthening the financial sector (Hellwig, 2009). Although some suffer from strong isomorphism, financial cooperatives tend to play a positive role in the banking sector, focusing more on retail banking, taking lower risks and increasing systemic stability (Hesse and Cihák, 2007; Ayadi et al., 2010). They are one of the earliest and most widespread forms of alternative financial institutions across the world (Hollis and Sweetman, 1998; Fonteyne, 2007). In December 2013, financial cooperatives served around 208 million members in 103 countries (WOCCU, 2014).1

This paper focuses on cooperative finance and argues that financial cooperatives can be considered as human-made common goods. Recognizing them as such helps to design innovative mechanisms, rules or legislation to protect them against destruction or isomorphism. This paper's outcomes are twofold: first, based on the case of financial cooperatives, it shows that the common nature of human-made goods can be rooted in their common-property regime. It actually argues that common-property regime can create common goods. Second, this paper highlights that considering financial cooperatives as common goods enables development and justifies adequate mechanisms in order to preserve their nature. In particular, it presents two major mechanisms that draw upon this concept: the common bond and the asset lock principle.

Methodology

To show that cooperative finance can be seen as common goods, we mobilize Ostrom's theoretical framework on common goods' nature and property regime (Ostrom, 1990).

We first refer to the economists' definition of the nature of goods and to Ostrom's characterization of common pool resources. We argue that common goods' definition should be interpreted in a broad way in order to define a new generation of commons that are not only natural, but also human-made goods. In particular, we apply Ostrom's framework to financial cooperatives and analyze the common resource system behind these institutions as well as the rivalrous resource units generated by this system (Ostrom et al., 1993; Ostrom, 1999; Hess and Ostrom, 2006).

We then demonstrate that financial cooperatives are common-property regimes characterized by the absence of alienation rights (Schlager & Ostrom, 1992). In particular, there is an intergenerational endowment: the resources system is inherited from past generations to be transferred to future ones (Davis, 2001; Birchall, 2013). The general reserve is built through retained earning accumulated over previous years. Individual members do not own the total value of their financial cooperative. Contrary to stock value, which should theoretically correspond to all actualized future benefits generated by an organization, cooperatives' shares only have a nominal value. We then proceed to a systematic comparison between cooperatives' principles and the set of design principles Ostrom has identified as required to ensure a sustainable governance of common-pool resources. We show that early financial cooperatives used to satisfy Ostrom's design principles, but no longer did when they became larger structures (Guinnane, 2001; Guinnane, 2003).

This demonstration first highlights that the nature and the property regime tend to overlap when we refer to human-made common goods. Second, it enables us to identify and justify mechanisms that tend to preserve the common nature of financial cooperatives. In particular, we identify two major mechanisms: the common bond and asset lock principle.

Bibliography

Armendáriz, B. and Morduch, J. (2010). The Economics of Microfinance. MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, London.

Ayadi, R., Llewelyn, D.T., Schmidt, R.H., Arbak E. and de Groen, W.P. (2010). Investigating Diversity in the Banking Sector in Europe: Key Developments, Performance and Role of Cooperative Banks, Centre for European Policy Studies (CEPS), Brussels.

Banerjee, A., Besley, T., and Guinnane, T. (1994). Thy Neighbor's Keeper the Design of a Credit Cooperative with Theory and Test. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(2), 491-515.

Birchall, J. (2013). Resilience in a downturn: The power of financial cooperatives. International Labour Office. - Geneva: ILO.

Borzaga, C. Depedri, S. and Tortia, E. (2009). Testing the distributive effects of social enterprises: the case of Italy. Working-Paper Euricse.

Branch, B., and Baker, C. (2000). Overcoming Credit Union Governance Problems. In Westley, G., & Branch, B. (ed.). Safe Money: Building Effective Credit Union in Latin America. Inter American Development Bank, Washington, 203-226.

Bundt, T., Chiesa, J.F. and Keating, B.P. (1989). Common Bond Type and Credit Union Behavior. Review of Social Economy, 47(1), 27-42.

Davis, K. (2001). Credit Union Governance and Survival of the Cooperative Form. Journal of Financial Services Research, 19(2-3), 197-210.

De Moor, T. (2011). From Common Pastures to Global Commons: a Historical Perspective on Interdisciplinary Approaches to Commons. Natures Sciences Sociétés, 19 (4), 422-431.

Fonteyne, W. (2007). Cooperatives Banks in Europe – Policy Issues. International Monetary Fund – Working Paper 07/159.

Frame, S., Karels, G. and McClatchey, C. (2002). The Effect of the Common Bond and Membership Expansion on Credit Union Risk. Financial Review, 37(4), 613-636.

Guinnane, T. (2001). Cooperatives as Information Machines: German Rural Credit Cooperatives, 1883-1914. Journal of Economic History, 61(02), 366-389.

Guinnane, T. (2003). A Friend and Advisor: External Auditing and Confidence in Germany's Credit Cooperatives, 1889-1914. Business History Review, 77(2), 235-264.

Hansmann, H. (1996). The ownership of enterprise. The Belknap Press of Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Hardin, G. (1968). The Tragedy of the Commons. Science, 162, 1243-1248.

Hellwig, M. (2009). Systemic Risk in the Financial Sector: An Analysis of the SubprimeMortgage Financial Crisis. De Economist, 157, 129–207.

Hess, C., & Ostrom, E. (2003). Ideas, Artifacts, and Facilities : Information as a CommonPool Resource. Law and Contemporary Problems, 66, 111-146.

Hesse, H., & Cihák, M. (2007). Cooperative Banks and Financial Stability. International Monetary Fund (IMF)–WP, N°07/2

Hollis, A. and Sweetman, A. (1998). Microcredit: What Can We Learn from the Past? World Development, 26(10), 1875-1891.

Hudon, M. and Meyer, C. (2013). Microfinance and common goods: A study of Brazilian community development banks. WP-CEB, 13(049), 38p. ICA – International Co-operative Alliance, 2014, www.ica.coop

Kotz, H., & Nagel, J. (2002). Les banques du secteur coopératif allemand sont-elles construites sur un avantage comparatif déclinant ? Revue d'économie financière, 67, 57-72.

Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons. The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge (NY): Cambridge University Press.

Ostrom, E. (1995). Constituting Social Capital and Collective action, in Robert O. Keohane and Elinor Ostrom (eds), Local Commons and Global Interdependence, Sage Publications, 125–1.

Ostrom, E., Gardner, R. and Walker, J. (1993). Rules, Games, and Common-Pool Resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Poteete A., Janssen, M. and Ostrom, E. (1968). Working Together: Collective Action, the Commons, and Multiple Methods in Practice, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Schlager, E. and Ostrom, E. (1992). Property Rights Regimes and Natural Resources: A Conceptual Analysis, Land Economics, 68, 249-262.

Vivero Pol, J.L. (2013). Food as a commons: reframing the narrative of the food system. SSRN working paper. April 2013. WOCCU – World Council of Credit Unions, 2014, www.woccu.org



  • Autre
Personnes connectées : 2 Flux RSS